America Has A Stadium Problem

Grand Potentate

Supporter of Possible Sexual Deviants
Moderator
Messages
40,355
This is a fascinating look at how cities and taxpayers are continually screwed by financing stadiums.

http://www.psmag.com/business-economics/america-has-a-stadium-problem-62665/
America Has a Stadium Problem

  • by Aaron Gordon
  • July 17, 2013
PPL-Park.jpg


If it were its own country, Chester, Pennsylvania’s per capita income would rank between Turkey and Dominica. On average, its residents are poorer than those of Uruguay, Lebanon, and Antigua and Barbuda. The city has been part of a program for economically distressed communities since 1995. And in 2010, PPL Park, a $117 million soccer stadium, was opened in Chester’s southwest corner, overlooking the Delaware River. With 97 percent of funding coming from the public, that’s $3,334.90 for every man, woman, and child in Chester.

Over the past 20 years, 101 new sports facilities have opened in the United States—a 90-percent replacement rate—and almost all of them have received direct public funding. The typical justification for a large public investment to build a stadium for an already-wealthy sports owner has to do with creating jobs or growing the local economy, which sound good to the median voter. “If I had to sum up the typical [public] perspective,” Neil deMause, co-author of Field of Schemes and editor of the blog by the same title—the go-tos on the ongoing stadium subsidy story—told me via email, “I’d guess it’d be something along the lines of ‘I don’t want my tax money going to rich fat cats, but anything that creates jobs is good, and man that Jeffrey Loria sure is a jerk, huh?’” This confused mindset has resulted in public coffers getting raided. The question is whether taxpayers have gotten anything in return.
All in all, building a stadium is a poor use of a few hundred million dollars.

Economists have long known stadiums to be poor public investments. Most of the jobs created by stadium-building projects are either temporary, low-paying, or out-of-state contracting jobs—none of which contribute greatly to the local economy. (Athletes can easily circumvent most taxes in the state in which they play.) Most fans do not spend additional money as a result of a new stadium; they re-direct money they would have spent elsewhere on movies, dining, bowling, tarot-card reading, or other businesses. And for every out-of-state fan who comes into the city on game day and buys a bucket of Bud Light Platinum, another non-fan decides not to visit and purchases his latte at the coffee shop next door. All in all, building a stadium is a poor use of a few hundred million dollars.
This isn’t news, by any stretch, but it turns out we’re spending even more money on stadiums than we originally thought. In her new book Public/Private Partnerships for Major League Sports Facilities, Judith Grant Long, associate professor of Urban Planning at the Harvard University Graduate School of Design, shatters previous conceptions of just how much money the public has poured into these deals. By the late ’90s, the first wave of damning economic studies conducted by Robert Baade and Richard Dye, James Quirk and Rodney Fort, and Roger Noll and Andrew Zimbalist came to light, but well afterwards, from 2001 to 2010, 50 new sports facilities were opened, receiving $130 million more, on average, than those opened in the preceding decade. (All figures from Long’s book adjusted for 2010 dollars.) In the 1990s, the average public cost for a new facility was estimated at $142 million, but by the end of the 2000s, that figure jumped to $241 million: an increase of 70 percent.

Economists have also been, according to Long, drastically underestimating the true cost of these projects. They fail to consider public subsidies for land and infrastructure, the ongoing costs of operations, capital improvements (we need a new scoreboard!), municipal services (all those traffic cops), and foregone property taxes (almost every major-league franchise located in the U.S. does not pay property taxes “due to a legal loophole with questionable rationale” as the normally value-neutral Long put it). Due to these oversights, Long calculates that economists have been underestimating public subsidies for sports facilities by 25 percent, raising the figure to $259 million per facility in operation during the 2010 season.

All the while, American cities, counties, and states continue to struggle. Glendale, Arizona, may actually sell City Hall so they can afford to keep subsidizing a hockey team that few people actually pay to see. Detroit isn’t exactly the paragon of fiscal responsibility, with its Emergency Manager—they have an honest-to-god “emergency manager”—offering a stern warning:
In a report to be presented to Michigan’s treasurer on Monday, Kevyn D. Orr, the emergency manager appointed in March to take over operations here, described long-term obligations of at least $15 billion, unsustainable cash flow shortages and miserably low credit ratings that make it difficult to borrow.​
But, they’re somehow on the verge of finding $450 million for a new hockey arena.
And in Hamilton County, Ohio, where a combined $805 million in taxpayer money built the new football and baseball stadiums, police and education budgets have been slashed, while one in seven people live below the poverty line.
Why, then, do we keep paying?

THE BASIC EVOLUTION BEHIND subsidies for sports stadiums is as follows: owner wants new stadium to make more money and increase the value of the franchise. Owner threatens to move team. Politicians save face by pretending they won’t offer millions of dollars in subsidies. Politicians eventually offer millions of dollars in subsidies and keep the team in the city. If there’s a justification for all this, it comes from the concept of a public good.
“The traditional definition of a public good is that the benefits aren’t scarce, they’re non-rival and non-excludable, so the consumption by one person doesn’t limit the consumption by someone else,” Professor J.C. Bradbury, a sports economist at Kennesaw State University and author of Hot Stove Economics, told me over the phone. “So if I’m happy Charlotte has a basketball team, that doesn’t make anyone else less happy.” The stadium itself, though, is a private good. There are only a limited number of seats, and if my ass is in Section 101, Row V, Seat 21, your ass isn’t.
Still, the thinking goes, a fan can enjoy a team without giving the franchise a penny. If you don’t buy Sunday Ticket, don’t attend any games, and don’t purchase any merchandise, then your favorite football team won’t see any of your money, no matter how passionately you follow them. But how do you quantify this? This is where Contingent Valuation Method (CVM), a survey method originally designed by environmental economists to value public park space or clean air, comes into play.
CVM asks people a hypothetical question: suppose their local team was going to move if they didn’t get a new arena. How much would you be willing to pay per year in higher taxes in order to keep that team?

Professor Bruce K. Johnson of Centre College, one of the best-known practitioners of this method, has repeated the CVM technique in various cities, and the results are almost unanimous: the willingness to pay is much smaller than the typical stadium subsidy, about one-fifth on average.
The theory goes that the subsidies ought to be highest in cities where there is only one major league team because it contributes most to civic pride in making the city “major league” and bringing national respect and attention. But the data doesn’t back that up. “[In Jacksonville, surveying the Jaguars] it was something like 75 percent of respondents said ‘yes, this makes us a major league city, it makes us proud to live here,’” Johnson said. “But way less than half the people were willing to pay anything in the way of higher taxes to keep the Jaguars in town … it comes out to be on the order of between $20 to 30 million.” Jacksonville subsidized EverBank Field to the tune of $260 million in 2010 dollars by Judith Grant Long’s calculations, with another $50 million for a new scoreboard on the way.

Professor Johnson has shown there’s perhaps a very real justification for public subsidies to even out the true value a sports team brings to a city—even if they often don’t. But, as deMause told me, “I’m a sports fan, and I’d be the first to agree that there’s absolutely a non-economic value to having a sports team in a city. The question is, how much is that worth? Would your city benefit more from devoting $300 million to a new sports facility or, say, from $300 million worth of extra spending on schools?”
We waste $20 on lots of things all the time. What’s one more stadium?

PROFESSOR JOHNSON HASN’T SURVEYED the Baltimore area, but whether they were willing to or not, Baltimoreans are paying about $20 per capita per year for Camden Yards. Camden Yards rejuvenated baseball in Baltimore and spurred a trend of new retro-style baseball stadiums with modern amenities across the league, making baseball owners everywhere all the richer. And it’s why stadiums continue to be built with limited opposition.
In the world of stadium financing, the few people who stand to gain millions (or billions) from subsidies (owners, developers, contractors, leagues) will invest heavily in lobbyists and campaigning efforts to see that their project is approved, whereas regular voters who only stand to lose $20 per year will invest very little in fighting an issue they may or may not care about. Public choice economics (and common sense) say this is a terrible way to decide how to allocate tax dollars because it kind of goes against the whole democracy thing. Unfortunately, more and more often, it seems to be the way tax dollars actually are allocated.

When I asked Professor Bradbury if he thinks the issue of stadium financing is fundamentally a public choice problem, he said, “You have classic concentrated benefits and dispersed costs, and politicians have time preferences. They want to get re-elected now, and paying it off later is someone else’s problem.” While Professor Johnson was more direct: “I think that’s really what’s going on here.” He recalled that voters in Pittsburgh initially voted down referendums on funding new stadiums for the Pirates and the Steelers, but they got built anyway (which is not an uncommon occurrence).
The really bad news: Public choice problems are incredibly hard to solve. As Professor Johnson pointed out to me, people care about all sorts of things, almost always more than they care about a small amount of tax revenue that may or may not go to a billionaire sports owner. The principle of the matter is gross—the rich taking from everyone through tax dollars to build a new playhouse so they can be worth more money—but people don’t care for a very rational reason. We would rather concern ourselves with supporting a candidate who will let us have an abortion/not let us have an abortion or any other seemingly more important issue. We waste $20 on lots of things all the time. What’s one more stadium?

Except it goes beyond that. The problem arises when our children become undereducated, our police forces understaffed, and our firehouses emptied while stadiums are built with those same dollars. The problem becomes an epidemic when it’s $31 billion-with-a-B spent by American taxpayers subsidizing privately-owned stadiums, and a merely 20-year-old stadium is being replaced months after the city it’s in threatened to raise taxes or shrink the budget by $20 million. The problem becomes unsolvable when voters rarely get to actually vote on the issue, and when they vote “no,” the stadiums get built anyway.

IN THE BACKGROUND OF PPL Park’s beautiful Delaware River-front view sits the Commodore Barry Bridge, which could be mistaken for a much more famous bridge if you didn’t know any better. After the game, everyone makes their way to the highway that spans the bridge, not spending a dime in Chester; there’s nowhere to spend any money, really, other than a place called “Just Pizza,” where I suspect bad things would happen if you asked for a sandwich. When I was there last month, we passed by a row of vacated houses. Outside one house, by the side of the road, was a mountain of garbage almost as high as the two-story structure itself. Car after car filled with soccer fans passed by this monument to Chester as quickly as the traffic cop would allow them; they just wanted to get to the highway.

You’ve heard about all the ways in which sports are a metaphor for society, how the crack of a bat on a hot summer afternoon represents something great about the workaday spirit of the American life, and whatever else. But as I drove out of Chester, that Kilimanjaro of garbage was no metaphor. Those 117 million dollars built a soccer stadium instead of helping whoever left that pile of waste on the side of the street keep their house, instead of hiring someone to clean it up, instead of addressing a whole bunch of other more pressing matters for the city than a new sports venue. Yet we keep going to the games, driving by the garbage and trying our best not to think too hard about how it got there because the stadium is just around the corner, the highway just around the bend.
 
As an Amazon Associate we earn from qualifying purchases.
This kind of stuff helped spark the Brazil riots. Stadiums are not a fantastic investment for struggling economies where they'll never be used again. At least in the US w/ a growing sports industry they have a chance to recoup a bit of this money.
 
Barring some natural monopoly utilty, the government has zero reason to spend (not invest) on private ventures. If stadiums were so lucrative, private investment would be all over it instead of coming hat in hand begging for taxpayer bucks.

Palin told the story of how Wasilla came begging her for a stadium. Seriously, the residents and not some construction firm. She claims she told them that she could, but taxes would go up and they replied 'oh hell yes, sock it to our poor asses, we want bread and circuses!'

Lemme just say that if I was looking for a town to live in, a giant-ass athletic stadium would be a major disincentive. Weekend traffic of rowdy drunks, no thanks.
 
Also, I'd like to point out that oftentimes, sports organizations give back endlessly to the community, whether it's donating used equipment, or volunteering, or youth camps for underprivileged kids, or fundraising for local charities, or the many other ways that they improve life for people outside of pure entertainment or money. Are they making millions of dollars to play a game? Sure. But then even in a worst case scenario they get DUI's, or murder someone and spend a million dollars on lawyers!

They could be doing these things without public monies as well.
 
Where the jobs are.

Sports teams, just like many other businesses go where the tax breaks and incentives are. If you are not giving them these, they will move on, because someone else will.

Yes, but if we got rid of them all together, as we damn well should, then what?
 
Get rid of what, tax breaks and incentives for corporations? Good luck with that. I'm pretty sure that's called "The end of the American economy".
No. Get rid of the use of public funds for sports teams.
 
As I already stated, government should only be subsidizing business if there is no other alternative. There are tons of alternatives to an expensive professional sports stadium.

If pro sports are threatening to leave for China, good riddance.
 
The same political classes that rail against poor people welfare are all for corporate welfare. You know, the bank bailouts, GM, etc. Then the ones that pretend education is important prioritze funding for sports arenas. Laughable.

I get that bonds pay for it, but what difference does it make where a tax is levied, it hits someone. Like taxing hotel rooms, airport taxes, etc. Dosn't affect you? Travel to th next town. Its so American, we sit around paying for eachothers shit.
 
I think my point is that its 4 cents here, a dollar there, pretty soon you're up to hundreds, if not thousands. Every hotel I go to has a hotel tax, why? Fuck the tourists. Its easy to avoid your own citys tax burden if you can take it out of the ass of an outsider. I've actually made many decisions in the past based on this sort of stuff. I'm not interested in the justifications. I am sick of is the political class coming up with every rationalization possible to get elected by saying that they didn't raise taxes, yet did.

My favorite is how the housing market went to shit, yet nobody around me payed less property tax, explain that!

Over time, this dynamic of making tax rates seem low yet fuck everyone that enters your juristiction over with hidden fees just makes me sick. I find it rather amusing that we pay all these taxes and then have to pay a fee for a drivers license, tags, identity cards, passports, you name it. Even sales tax on food now. Its just unsustainable.

You sound like you are pro stadium, III, like it or not. I personally avoid staidums whenever possible and I never buy anything inside, $10 for a goddam beer? GTFO, I'd rather booze at home. The reality of this problem is the same as with all other forms of corporate welfare... people buy the bullshit that its "good for the local economy". And its just not.
 
So his amounts to a glorified "all the other kids are doing it" with a bit of "or I'll take my ball and go home" bluffing?

A stadium is a place to sit and watch people play with balls. I can do that at any playground, any school. For free. Pro sports might as well be telecast from overseas, as the money has little to do with actual locale or the stupid stadium. Ticket sales is a blip of the revenue. A paltry sub-percentage of people in an area will ever set foot inside. Like big box stores, there huge externalized costs.

Don't get me started on cable television costs way too much almost entirely due to sports licensing fees.
 
And on top of that, stadiums get paid off. Schools never stop needing money.

Right. This is like road tolls. The road also gets paid off but the tolls never seem to disappear. Neither do the taxes, they just get re-purposed. Then another bond comes around and a new tax is created. "Paid off" is pure theater.

I'm not whining, III, my advice is to continously vote out candidates until they do what we ask, and do it properly.
 
Maybe I'm the weird one here, but while I don't enjoy paying taxes, I understand that it's a fundamental aspect of our society, and I understand them, know where my taxes go and what they are being used for. I understand that they help improve my surroundings. I can come to terms with paying billions of dollars in subsidies to corporations to do business in my city, because it makes my city better. Same for the arts, entertainment, and culture. Schools, busses, the port, I subsidize the shit out of. I'm generally ok with it because it makes my city better. I even subsidize ridiculous bike lanes that bicyclists don't even USE! (probably because I wish they would)

Federal taxes, I don't know that anyone understands, but state and local? That's easy stuff.


Your polyanna ideas about taxes are quaint. The reality is juristictions can operate on less than half of what they currently get if the money was used efficently. Just drive by any crew doing public works if you don't believe me. I've yet to see one where more than half the crew is working. I've never seen some much standing around.

For me, I wouldn't mind paying this shitload of money if it was actually used for something other than waste.
 
Doesn't happen around here. You must live somewhere that sucks.

You serious? There is a toll road near me that was built 35 years ago, it was paid after 15 or so. Toll is still there funding all kinds of other shit, and, comically, its increasing.
 
The toll road is not hypothetical, its right near my house. People have complained about the toll forever. Just a few years ago it was extended to cover some new public works project.

I'm a sports fan. But I'm not a fan of "fund it all". The US deficit happened because of this. If an owner of a sports team wants a new staduim, let him pay for it. Its not as if I can call the local govt and say "hey, buy me a hybrid car so I can keep the air in town clean". So I believe your mistaken, I enjoy sports but don't believe the pubic should be threatened into paying for it.
 
http://www.fieldofschemes.com/2013/...till-wont-let-detroit-spend-on-anything-else/

Need more evidence that the Detroit Red Wings arena subsidy is really, truly going ahead despite the city of Detroit being bankrupt? The state just approved the city’s development arm to sell $284.5 million in bonds for the project:
[Gov. Rick] Snyder paid a visit to the Strategic Fund board moments after it approved the deal and said the new arena is very exciting for Michigan.
“Detroit’s really on a comeback path,” he said. “I think Detroit is absolutely poised for a bright exciting future. This is just another proof point in that exercise.”…
He said he can justify the use of tax dollars on the project, given Detroit’s finances, because it is about investing in the city’s future.
“This is a catalyst project,” Snyder said. “This is going to be where the Red Wings are. Who doesn’t get fired up in Detroit about the Red Wings? Come on now, the people that are criticizing are people from outside of Michigan. This is something that is important to all of us.”​
Only about 55% of the public bonds will be repaid by the Detroit Development Authority out of city property taxes — the rest will come from Red Wings owner Mike Ilitch — so that would keep the city’s subsidy down to a mere $156 million. Still, you can’t help wondering if the state government that is forcing Detroit to consider selling off the paintings in its art museum might be a bit hasty in not questioning whether a new hockey arena is the best “investment in the city’s future” that the city can come up with. Even if, say, a working school system might not get people as “fired up.” Maybe if the schools sold souvenir jerseys…
Meanwhile, it looks like somebody has decided that so long as there’s public money being handed around for stadiums, he’s going to try to get a piece of the action:
The Toronto-based owners of the Pontiac Silverdome have submitted a bid for the Wayne County justice department sites in hopes of opening a stadium for a Detroit Major League Soccer team, along with a mall, residential space and office towers.​
MLS says it will “monitor” the Silverdome owner’s plans. Which, given that it’s this guy, sounds about right.
 
http://www.slate.com/blogs/moneybox...eal_better_than_most_still_pretty_rotten.html
The Dubious Economics of Stadium Subsidies, D.C. United Edition

  • by Matthew Yglesias
  • July 25, 2013
cq5dam.web.1280.1280.png

dc%20united%20stadium.png.CROP.original-original.png

Gene Thorp / The Washington Post
My friend the fanatical D.C. United fan is eager to point out to me that by the standards of stadium boondoggles, the new deal between the D.C. government and the D.C. United soccer team looks pretty good.
And indeed it does look pretty good. Basically, the city is going to swap an existing municipal builiding that sits atop some very valuable land in order to acquire some not-so-valuable land. The not-so-valuable land will be used to build a stadium (D.C. United wins!), the existing municipal building will be turned into a mixed-used condos-and-retail structure (jobs! residents! tax revenue!), and the city agencies will be relocated to a new facility near the Anacostia Metro where they'll help contribute to what's hopefully a rennaissance for retailers in the Historic Anacostia downtownish area. That'd be a change for the better relative to what we have now.
But the fact that this counts as a pretty reasonable stadium deal as far as stadium deals go just goes to show how dumb stadium deals are. The building the city is giving up as part of this deal, the Reeves Center, has an estimated value of $100 million. The D.C. United soccer franchise is worth about $50 million. According to D.C. United, the reason a new stadium is necessary is that they can't earn profits at RFK stadium but will be able to turn a profit at the new facility. So we're talking about investing a sum of money that exceeds the present value of the team in order to take an action that will have substantial private benefits for the team's owner. Now it's conceivable that keeping the team in D.C. has some public benefits that make it worth doing, but for the price D.C. is paying the city could literally buy the enter soccer team which would be a much better way of obtaining the public benefits.
Note that while we superficially have a story about sports subsidies here, the real devil's work is being done by accounting. Imagine we had already sold the Reeves Center to a private developer and moved the government offices across the river and had $100 million sitting around in a room somewhere. Now we're debating what to do with the $100 million. The option "use it to buy land and then give it for free to a soccer team" would probably not seem very appealing to people. But since selling the Reeves Center and moving the offices is a very good idea, including that swap as part of the bundle rather than considering it separately makes the plan look pretty good.
 
You keep saying things like "The US Deficit happened because of this" and random other just plain incorrect shit. I'd wish you'd stop. I hate to be the one to break your convenient little world belief that public funding for stadiums is the source of all evil, but it's nearly impossible to hold a conversation with you about it when all you do is regurgitate hyperbole. The US deficit has little to nothing to do with municipalities bonding money from private investors to build amenities, and then the public of that municipality paying those investors back. Did you just find some tea party pamphlet in the bathroom or something where you get all your facts from? In fact, the very definition of a deficit is spending more money than you are taking in, which in the case of construction bonds that get repaid with any revenue stream, including public tax money, usage fees, fundraising, service surcharges, etc - is not a long term deficit AT ALL. In fact it is good for the cities credit rating and may help the taxpayers save money on future bonding projects. Is it a short term deficit? Yes, but all public works are a short term deficit, just like every time you spend money while simultaneously not making that money at the exact same second - it's a short term deficit.

I call it a hypothetical bridge because
A: you probably have no concept as to what the actual revenue of the tolls vs operating cost on the bridge is, or even what the statute of the toll agreement was. You assume that the toll was instituted to repay the constructions bonds only. That may not be the case. Also, you fail to mention what share of the tolls even go to things like operational costs (if any), or what impact the tolls revenue have on the overall budget. You are just guessing or ignoring all of that. It's quite possible that the toll bridge saves you tax money, and that it's tolls were instituted to negate a direct taxpayer outlay and deficit, not the other way around.

B: You aren't mentioning whether your municipality just re-purposed all/part of the toll without any public input or not. As I mentioned earlier, there are laws about specifically that in many places. If there was a vote about re-purposing the tolls, your point is moot. If there is no such law in your area - go make one. That's how ours got passed. Some dude fed up with the city and state re-purposing bond taxes at some point in the past passed a referendum or initiative that made a public vote necessary. I can tell you that both the Rangers Ballpark at Arlington and the new Cowboys Stadium were funded exactly this way, have/are being paid off early, and with a current surplus of funds. Re-purposing the Rangers Ballpark tax into the Cowboys tax required a vote.

So there may be an actual bridge, but right now, the bridge, and the situation you are describing to me is only hypothetical. Judging from your comments on the rest of the things in this thread, I'm inclined to believe that you probably have no actual idea if the toll on the bridge is good or bad, and just default to bad because someone else equally unqualified told you it was bad.

So #1, its a toll road. Not a bridge. And I'm well plugged into my community so I know the toll has been repurposed 4 times to be exact. The lastest iteration started 7 years ago. It required a vote within the govt, there was no referrendum. The most recent public work had a controversy associated with the way the project was implemented. Bechtel saw to it that the project was done their way and not how the community wanted it, nobody around here is happy. In fact my local represntative specifically told me she was against the Bechtel proposal and then voted for it. She was voted out in '08 because of it.

#2, my comment about federal deficits is analogous, no suggestion was made this piles on the national dept. What I am pointing to is that its a similar kind of thinking: gimme cool shit now and I will pay for it later/make someone else pay for it.

We obviously disagree on public funding of private business such as stadiums, and you're kind of aggressive so I wanted to clarify these 2 red herrings and I'll leave it here.
 
More on the DC Soccer Stadium:
http://www.fieldofschemes.com/2013/...ost-taxpayers-200m-give-all-revenues-to-team/
D.C. United deal would cost taxpayers $200m, give all revenues to team

Posted on July 26, 2013 by Neil deMause
The D.C. United stadium term sheet is now online for public perusal, and a quick scan provides a few glimpses into how the deal would play out:
  • D.C. estimates that the “total value” of securing land for the project, doing any environmental remediation, etc., would be $140 million. Given the complicated land swap that would be required, it’s not entirely clear whether this would actually mean D.C. spending $140 million in cash, but it’s a reasonable starting point as guesstimates go.
  • D.C. United would pay $1 to rent the site, then would “develop, construct, manage and operate” the stadium. In other words, would pay neither rent nor property taxes. D.C. United would make payments in lieu of property taxes, but those would then be funneled back to the team to pay off its stadium construction costs — presumably in order to take advantage of the tax dodge first employed by the New York Yankees.
  • D.C. United would get all revenues from the stadium, including, presumably, non-soccer uses like concerts.
  • If D.C. United turns more than a “reasonable profit,” as yet to be defined, then the District will receive a “portion” of the excess profits, also as yet to be defined. The Washington City Paper calls this an “interesting wrinkle,” but without details it’s tough to know whether this would amount to real money or is just a windfall profits clause that sounds nice but would never come into play in reality, because you know how sports teams are about keeping their books.
  • I can’t find anything about the sales and use tax kickback that the Washington Post reported yesterday, but that may be a separate negotiation.
In short, then, we’re still looking at D.C. paying around $200 million, give or take an unknown amount, in exchange for the team promising to play in a stadium for which it keeps all the revenues, unlike the lease the team has currently at RFK Stadium. It doesn’t sound that great when you put it that way, which is no doubt one reasons why the apparent cost has been somewhat obscured by using this complicated land swap deal, where the District can claim that it’s just taking the opportunity to redevelop a bunch of plots of land at once. But as Matt Yglesias points out at Slate:
Note that while we superficially have a story about sports subsidies here, the real devil’s work is being done by accounting. Imagine we had already sold the Reeves Center to a private developer and moved the government offices across the river and had $100 million sitting around in a room somewhere. Now we’re debating what to do with the $100 million. The option “use it to buy land and then give it for free to a soccer team” would probably not seem very appealing to people. But since selling the Reeves Center and moving the offices is a very good idea, including that swap as part of the bundle rather than considering it separately makes the plan look pretty good.​
It’d be nice if, say, the Washington Post would analyze the deal on that basis, and see if it then makes sense. But I’m thinking naaaaaah.
 
http://america.aljazeera.com/articles/2013/8/21/pay-to-play.html


Do cities gain from subsidizing sports teams?
by Neil deMause

August 21, 2013 5:00AM ET
Funding is often cut for parks and libraries to help teams pay their bills


The National Hockey League season doesn't start for another three weeks, but already hockey fans in Glendale, Ariz., are counting an unexpected victory. Four years after the Phoenix Coyotes went bankrupt and were taken over by the league, prompting endless rumors that the struggling franchise would relocate to Quebec, Seattle or parts unknown, new owners were approved this month who have promised to keep the team in Arizona.

It's a victory, though, that will come at a high price. To secure the sale, the Glendale city council agreed to a new lease that requires the city to pay the Coyotes' owners $15 million a year as an "arena management fee." If the deal runs its full 15-year course — not a given, because the new lease allows the team to leave town if it’slosing money after five years — the Coyotes' new owners, a pair of Canadian investment bankers, will end up collecting more from the city of Glendale to run the team than the $170 million they're spending to buy it in the first place.

City officials say they had little choice. Glendale mayor Jerry Weiers, who in his acceptance speech last fall warned the Coyotes, "Glendale is not your cash register," has now resigned himself to paying for pro sports, saying, "The council made its decision, and my job at this point is to do everything in my power to make this thing a success." His predecessor, Elaine Scruggs, insisted that paying the Coyotes was cheaper than letting the team leave: "What shall we do — lock it up, turn off the lights and then pay the debt on the arena?"

The answer, say many economists and sports business experts, is very likely yes. There's no way a city like Glendale will see enough of a boost to its local economy to make lease subsidies pay off. And, they warn, the Coyotes deal is a sign of a new trend in the sports industry: After a 20-year period during which, according to Harvard researcher Judith Grant Long, about $18 billion in public money was spent on a wave of new stadiums and arenas, team owners looking for a leg up on their competition are now demanding additional cash to run the buildings they got for free.

"They always do come up with clever little tricks," says Rick Eckstein, sociology professor at Villanova University and co-author of the book Public Dollars, Private Stadiums. "Just when we think we’ve seen it all, they come up with something else."

This summer's new lease isn't the first time that Glendale has anted up public cash for its hockey team. The suburb of 230,000 people was already on the hook for $9 million a year in debt payments on its new arena, a building for which the team's owners paid only $1 a year in rent. (Glendale also spent $200 million on Camelback Ranch, a spring-training baseball facility for the Los Angeles Dodgers and Chicago White Sox.) In 2010, after the Coyotes' bankruptcy, Scruggs poured in an additional $50 million in management fees over two years, raiding its landfill, sanitation, water and sewer funds to raise the cash.

The result of all this sports spending has been a massive hit to the city's budgetat a time when Glendale was already furloughing firefighters, closing public pools and shortening public libraries' hours. Last month's Coyotes lease subsidy came shortly after the Glendale council discussed a proposal to sell off its city hall to help pay for the previous round of Coyotes payments.

"Our police and fire departments were the first ones that started seeing their budget cut back," says Ken Jones, a Glendale resident who led several unsuccessful attempts to force a public vote that could have overturned the Coyotes lease deal. "Libraries were hit pretty hard. They raised our water bills 80 percent, our sales tax was raised, and our property tax was raised. They have robbed the things that people really expect to get from their taxes in order to keep supporting sports."

Learning from the Saints
The first sports team owner to cash in on this pay-to-play tactic was the New Orleans Saints' Tom Benson, who in 2001 capitalized on rumors that he was considering moving his NFL team to convince the state of Louisiana to pay him$186.5 millionover the next 10 years to keep playing at the Superdome. In 2010, the owners of the Indiana Pacers basketball team followed suit by demanding — and receiving — $30 million in "operating subsidies"over three years to remain at Conseco Fieldhouse, the arena that the city of Indianapolis had spent $183 million to build nine years earlier. (As in Glendale, Pacers owner Herb Simon, a billionaire real estate developer, paid just $1 a year rent.)

To pay off the initial Pacers arena cost — plus the $650 million that it sank into a new stadium for the Colts football team — Indianapolis' Capital Improvement Board had already cut off all of its arts and tourism grants the year before. To help fill the new gap, Mayor Greg Ballard funneled city property-tax revenues to the board, even as he asked city agencies to reduce library hours and close public pools because of budget shortfalls.

"Indianapolis might be a great place to visit, but it should be a better place to live," says Pat Andrews, a longtime Indianapolis community activist and blogger who has closely followed the Pacers deal. In addition to cuts to parks, transit and other services, she notes, the city police force has stopped recruiting new officers because of budget cuts, and murders have risen dramatically this year. "The basic services of the city are suffering at the same time the Simons and [Colts owner Jim] Irsay are making out like bandits."

Simon, meanwhile, agreed only to keep the Pacers in town through 2013 in exchange for his $30 million in cash. The city's Capital Improvement Board has since negotiated a one-year lease extension — along with yet another $10 million in payments to the Pacers — while it works out a long-term deal, one that Andrews worries will cement annual operating subsidies in place for good. (CIB officials declined to comment for this story.)

Even team owners building new stadiums have begun seeking annual operating subsidies.Earlier this year, when Atlanta agreed to provide billionaire Atlanta Falcons owner (and Home Depot founder) Arthur Blank with $200 million in hotel tax money to help pay for a new stadium to replace the 20-year-old Georgia Dome, it tacked on an additional bonus: Any leftover hotel tax money after the first $200 million would spill over into a so-called waterfall fund that Blank could then tap for any future maintenance or operating expenses. Estimated cost: an extra $300 million.

They have robbed the things that people really expect to get from their taxes in order to keep supporting sports.
The Atlanta deal is a perfect example of how subsidies are increasingly buried deep within lease agreements that are seldom if ever carefully scrutinized by politicians or the media. The waterfall fund was only revealed when a local business writer exposed it on her own blog — and even then, it was rarely mentioned in subsequent media stories or in legislative debates.

"You've really got to go through these deals in detail to figure out if they're getting [subsidies] or not," says West Virginia University economist Brad Humphreys. "It's not like the lease agreement says we're cutting you a check every year."

As a result, such hidden subsidies are on the rise, according to Harvard researcher Long's figures: The 121 North American major-league sports facilities in use during 2010, she found, cost taxpayers about $10 billion more than is commonly reported, thanks to the hidden costs of land, infrastructure, operating subsidies and lost property taxes. In some cases, teams effectivelypay negative rent, such as the Milwaukee Brewers, whose $1 million or so in annual rent on publicly built and owned Miller Park is dwarfed by the nearly $4 million a year in government checks to pay the team's yearly operating costs.

Milwaukee, which is the nation's 34th-largest TV market, is typical of the kinds of cities that end up providing their teams with annual cash payments, according to Long. "You've got Milwaukee, Cincinnati, Memphis, Oklahoma City, Charlotte," she says. "Small cities who were luring a team from somewhere else, or otherwise second- or third-tier cities, are the common denominator."

When Glendale first built a new arena to attract the Coyotes, says Serena Unrein of the Arizona Public Interest Research Group, "I think everyone looked at it with rose-colored glasses: 'This is going to be great; it'll put Glendale on the map.' The people in Glendale who were making the decisions saw all of the upside and none of the risk for taxpayers."

Less bang for the buck
Economists who've studied sports deals say that spending big to lure new teams, or keep old ones, almost never pays off. In one much-repeated study, Lake Forest College economist Robert A. Baade examined 30 cities that had recently built new sports venues. In 27, there was no measurable impact on per-capita income, while in the other three, income appeared to have gone down as a result. Even if the Pacers, say, had left town after being denied a new round of subsidies, studies indicate that the economic impacts would have been less than dire: When Humphreys and Dennis Coates of the University of Maryland looked at income data for cities that lost their teams, as well as during sports league strikes and lockouts, they found no significant effects. "The departure of a franchise in any sport," they wrote, "has never significantly lowered real per capita personal income in a metropolitan area."

Humphreys, in fact, says that operating subsidies like those handed out to the Coyotes and Pacers are likely to get even less bang for the buck than stadium cash, which at least might create a few thousand temporary construction jobs. "Not only that, but the operating subsidies are almost certainly coming out of general fund revenues," he says. "If there's a ticket tax or anything that looks like a user tax, at least then the people who are enjoying the benefits are paying. But if it's operating subsidies coming out of general fund revenues, that's money that could go to any other alternative use in the city, like education or public safety."

Even public money with strings attached could go to fill other city needs, say budget watchdogs. Ryan Splitlog of Common Cause Georgia, a nonprofit, nonpartisan citizens' lobby, notes that the money going to the Falcons comes from hotel-motel tax revenue that is designated for promoting tourism and convention business. "I think you could paint with a pretty wide brush stroke when talking about what that means for the city of Atlanta," he says, suggesting fixing the "atrocious" roads and sidewalks in the blocks surrounding the convention center campus as one example. "You could talk about infrastructure projects that improve the quality of life for people who actually live here. I think the public would get much more behind something like that."

Roads and sidewalks, though, lack the lobbying power of sports team owners. Both Eckstein and Long note that party affiliation makes little difference in sports deals, with Republican and Democratic mayors equally willing to back subsidies to teams. The key factor, say sociologist Eckstein and his co-author Kevin Delaney, is to have a strong "growth coalition" of business leaders pushing for them —as when Cincinnati's powerful local chamber of commerce helped raise $1 million for a "Keep Cincinnati a Major-League City" campaign to raise sales taxes for new stadiums for the Reds baseball team and Bengals NFL franchise, more than double the city's previous record spending on any ballot initiative.

Still, even Eckstein says he's still surprised at the continued willingness of mayors and city councils to hand out money to team owners time and again, even when the team already boasts a new publicly built stadium.

"It just defies all reason and rationality," he says. "You see the political graveyards filled with corpses of the politicians that supported these things — they get voted out of office, they end up working for the clubs. You'd figure that these people would be savvy enough to learn that it's not in their best political interest to support these things. But they keep doing it."
 
Figured this was the best place for this - a great piece by Gregg Easterbrook on how the NFL fleeces Americans:

http://www.theatlantic.com/magazine/archive/2013/10/how-the-nfl-fleeces-taxpayers/309448/

October 2013
How the NFL Fleeces Taxpayers
Taxpayers fund the stadiums, antitrust law doesn't apply to broadcast deals, the league enjoys nonprofit status, and Commissioner Roger Goodell makes $30 million a year. It's time to stop the public giveaways to America's richest sports league—and to the feudal lords who own its teams.
Gregg Easterbrook Sep 18 2013, 8:24 PM ET

Tweet
upload_2013-9-23_15-48-45.webp

upload_2013-9-23_15-48-45.webp

More
mag-article-large.jpg

Matt Lehman
Last year was a busy one for public giveaways to the National Football League. In Virginia, Republican Governor Bob McDonnell, who styles himself as a budget-slashing conservative crusader, took $4 million from taxpayers’ pockets and handed the money to the Washington Redskins, for the team to upgrade a workout facility. Hoping to avoid scrutiny, McDonnell approved the gift while the state legislature was out of session. The Redskins’ owner, Dan Snyder, has a net worth estimated by Forbes at $1 billion. But even billionaires like to receive expensive gifts.

Taxpayers in Hamilton County, Ohio, which includes Cincinnati, were hit with a bill for $26 million in debt service for the stadiums where the NFL’s Bengals and Major League Baseball’s Reds play, plus another $7 million to cover the direct operating costs for the Bengals’ field. Pro-sports subsidies exceeded the $23.6 million that the county cut from health-and-human-services spending in the current two-year budget (and represent a sizable chunk of the $119 million cut from Hamilton County schools). Press materials distributed by the Bengals declare that the team gives back about $1 million annually to Ohio community groups. Sound generous? That’s about 4 percent of the public subsidy the Bengals receive annually from Ohio taxpayers.

In Minnesota, the Vikings wanted a new stadium, and were vaguely threatening to decamp to another state if they didn’t get it. The Minnesota legislature, facing a $1.1 billion budget deficit, extracted $506 million from taxpayers as a gift to the team, covering roughly half the cost of the new facility. Some legislators argued that the Vikings should reveal their finances: privately held, the team is not required to disclose operating data, despite the public subsidies it receives. In the end, the Minnesota legislature folded, giving away public money without the Vikings’ disclosing information in return. The team’s principal owner, Zygmunt Wilf, had a 2011 net worth estimated at $322 million; with the new stadium deal, the Vikings’ value rose about $200 million, by Forbes’s estimate, further enriching Wilf and his family. They will make a token annual payment of $13 million to use the stadium, keeping the lion’s share of all NFL ticket, concession, parking, and, most important, television revenues.

After approving the $506 million handout, Minnesota Governor Mark Dayton said, “I’m not one to defend the economics of professional sports … Any deal you make in that world doesn’t make sense from the way the rest of us look at it.” Even by the standards of political pandering, Dayton’s irresponsibility was breathtaking.

In California, the City of Santa Clara broke ground on a $1.3 billion stadium for the 49ers. Officially, the deal includes $116 million in public funding, with private capital making up the rest. At least, that’s the way the deal was announced. A new government entity, the Santa Clara Stadium Authority, is borrowing $950 million, largely from a consortium led by Goldman Sachs, to provide the majority of the “private” financing. Who are the board members of the Santa Clara Stadium Authority? The members of the Santa Clara City Council. In effect, the city of Santa Clara is providing most of the “private” funding. Should something go wrong, taxpayers will likely take the hit.

The 49ers will pay Santa Clara $24.5 million annually in rent for four decades, which makes the deal, from the team’s standpoint, a 40-year loan amortized at less than 1 percent interest. At the time of the agreement, 30-year Treasury bonds were selling for 3 percent, meaning the Santa Clara contract values the NFL as a better risk than the United States government.

Although most of the capital for the new stadium is being underwritten by the public, most football revenue generated within the facility will be pocketed by Denise DeBartolo York, whose net worth is estimated at $1.1 billion, and members of her family. York took control of the team in 2000 from her brother, Edward DeBartolo Jr., after he pleaded guilty to concealing an extortion plot by a former governor of Louisiana. Brother and sister inherited their money from their father, Edward DeBartolo Sr., a shopping-mall developer who became one of the nation’s richest men before his death in 1994. A generation ago, the DeBartolos made their money the old-fashioned way, by hard work in the free market. Today, the family’s wealth rests on political influence and California tax subsidies. Nearly all NFL franchises are family-owned, converting public subsidies and tax favors into high living for a modern-day feudal elite.

Pro-football coaches talk about accountability and self-reliance, yet pro-football owners routinely binge on giveaways and handouts. A year after Hurricane Katrina hit New Orleans, the Saints resumed hosting NFL games: justifiably, a national feel-good story. The finances were another matter. Taxpayers have, in stages, provided about $1 billion to build and later renovate what is now known as the Mercedes-Benz Superdome. (All monetary figures in this article have been converted to 2013 dollars.) The Saints’ owner, Tom Benson, whose net worth Forbes estimates at $1.2 billion, keeps nearly all revenue from ticket sales, concessions, parking, and broadcast rights. Taxpayers even footed the bill for the addition of leather stadium seats with cup holders to cradle the drinks they are charged for at concession stands. And corporate welfare for the Saints doesn’t stop at stadium construction and renovation costs. Though Louisiana Governor Bobby Jindal claims to be an anti-spending conservative, each year the state of Louisiana forcibly extracts up to $6 million from its residents’ pockets and gives the cash to Benson as an “inducement payment”—the actual term used—to keep Benson from developing a wandering eye.

Twelve teams have turned a profit on stadium subsidies alone—receiving more money than they needed to build their facilities.
In NFL city after NFL city, this pattern is repeated. CenturyLink Field, where the Seattle Seahawks play, opened in 2002, with Washington State taxpayers providing $390 million of the $560 million construction cost. The Seahawks, owned by Paul Allen, one of the richest people in the world, pay the state about $1 million annually in rent in return for most of the revenue from ticket sales, concessions, parking, and broadcasting (all told, perhaps $200 million a year). Average people are taxed to fund Allen’s private-jet lifestyle.

The Pittsburgh Steelers, winners of six Super Bowls, the most of any franchise, play at Heinz Field, a glorious stadium that opens to a view of the serenely flowing Ohio and Allegheny Rivers. Pennsylvania taxpayers contributed about $260 million to help build Heinz Field—and to retire debt from the Steelers’ previous stadium. Most game-day revenues (including television fees) go to the Rooney family, the majority owner of the team. The team’s owners also kept the $75 million that Heinz paid to name the facility.

Judith Grant Long, a Harvard University professor of urban planning, calculates that league-wide, 70 percent of the capital cost of NFL stadiums has been provided by taxpayers, not NFL owners. Many cities, counties, and states also pay the stadiums’ ongoing costs, by providing power, sewer services, other infrastructure, and stadium improvements. When ongoing costs are added, Long’s research finds, the Buffalo Bills, Cincinnati Bengals, Cleveland Browns, Houston Texans, Indianapolis Colts, Jacksonville Jaguars, Kansas City Chiefs, New Orleans Saints, San Diego Chargers, St. Louis Rams, Tampa Bay Buccaneers, and Tennessee Titans have turned a profit on stadium subsidies alone—receiving more money from the public than they needed to build their facilities. Long’s estimates show that just three NFL franchises—the New England Patriots, New York Giants, and New York Jets—have paid three-quarters or more of their stadium capital costs.

Many NFL teams have also cut sweetheart deals to avoid taxes. The futuristic new field where the Dallas Cowboys play, with its 80,000 seats, go-go dancers on upper decks, and built-in nightclubs, has been appraised at nearly $1 billion. At the basic property-tax rate of Arlington, Texas, where the stadium is located, Cowboys owner Jerry Jones would owe at least $6 million a year in property taxes. Instead he receives no property-tax bill, so Tarrant County taxes the property of average people more than it otherwise would.

In his office at 345 Park Avenue in Manhattan, NFL Commissioner Roger Goodell must smile when Texas exempts the Cowboys’ stadium from taxes, or the governor of Minnesota bows low to kiss the feet of the NFL. The National Football League is about two things: producing high-quality sports entertainment, which it does very well, and exploiting taxpayers, which it also does very well. Goodell should know—his pay, about $30 million in 2011, flows from an organization that does not pay corporate taxes.

That’s right—extremely profitable and one of the most subsidized organizations in American history, the NFL also enjoys tax-exempt status. On paper, it is the Nonprofit Football League.

This situation came into being in the 1960s, when Congress granted antitrust waivers to what were then the National Football League and the American Football League, allowing them to merge, conduct a common draft, and jointly auction television rights. The merger was good for the sport, stabilizing pro football while ensuring quality of competition. But Congress gave away the store to the NFL while getting almost nothing for the public in return.

The 1961 Sports Broadcasting Act was the first piece of gift-wrapped legislation, granting the leagues legal permission to conduct television-broadcast negotiations in a way that otherwise would have been price collusion. Then, in 1966, Congress enacted Public Law 89‑800, which broadened the limited antitrust exemptions of the 1961 law. Essentially, the 1966 statute said that if the two pro-football leagues of that era merged—they would complete such a merger four years later, forming the current NFL—the new entity could act as a monopoly regarding television rights. Apple or ExxonMobil can only dream of legal permission to function as a monopoly: the 1966 law was effectively a license for NFL owners to print money. Yet this sweetheart deal was offered to the NFL in exchange only for its promise not to schedule games on Friday nights or Saturdays in autumn, when many high schools and colleges play football.

Public Law 89-800 had no name—unlike, say, the catchy USA Patriot Act or the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act. Congress presumably wanted the bill to be low-profile, given that its effect was to increase NFL owners’ wealth at the expense of average people.

While Public Law 89-800 was being negotiated with congressional leaders, NFL lobbyists tossed in the sort of obscure provision that is the essence of the lobbyist’s art. The phrase or professional football leagues was added to Section 501(c)6 of 26 U.S.C., the Internal Revenue Code. Previously, a sentence in Section 501(c)6 had granted not-for-profit status to “business leagues, chambers of commerce, real-estate boards, or boards of trade.” Since 1966, the code has read: “business leagues, chambers of commerce, real-estate boards, boards of trade, or professional football leagues.”

The insertion of professional football leagues into the definition of not-for-profit organizations was a transparent sellout of public interest. This decision has saved the NFL uncounted millions in tax obligations, which means that ordinary people must pay higher taxes, public spending must decline, or the national debt must increase to make up for the shortfall. Nonprofit status applies to the NFL’s headquarters, which administers the league and its all-important television contracts. Individual teams are for-profit and presumably pay income taxes—though because all except the Green Bay Packers are privately held and do not disclose their finances, it’s impossible to be sure.

For Veterans Day last year, the NFL announced that it would donate cash to military groups for each point scored in designated games. During NFL telecasts that weekend, the league was praised for its grand generosity. The total donation came to about $440,000. Annualized, NFL stadium subsidies and tax favors add up to perhaps $1 billion. So the NFL took $1 billion from the public, then sought praise for giving back $440,000—less than a tenth of 1 percent.

In the NFL, cynicism about public money starts at the top. State laws and IRS rules generally forbid the use of nonprofit status as a subterfuge for personal enrichment. Yet according to the league’s annual Form 990, in 2011, the most recent year for which numbers are available, the NFL paid a total of almost $60 million to its leading five executives.

Roger Goodell’s windfall has been justified on the grounds that the free market rewards executives whose organizations perform well, and there is no doubt that the NFL performs well as to both product quality—the games are consistently terrific—and the bottom line. But almost nothing about the league’s operations involves the free market. Taxpayers fund most stadium costs; the league itself is tax-exempt; television images made in those publicly funded stadiums are privatized, with all gains kept by the owners; and then the entire organization is walled off behind a moat of antitrust exemptions.

The reason NFL executives’ pay is known is that in 2008, the IRS moved to strengthen the requirement that 501(c)6 organizations disclose payments to top officers. The NFL asked Congress to grant pro football a waiver from the disclosure rule. During the lobbying battle, Joe Browne, then the league’s vice president for public affairs, told The New York Times, “I finally get to the point where I’m making 150 grand, and they want to put my name and address on the [disclosure] form so the lawyer next door who makes a million dollars a year can laugh at me.” Browne added that $150,000 does not buy in the New York area what it would in “Dubuque, Iowa.” The waiver was denied. Left no option, the NFL revealed that at the time, Browne made about $2 million annually.

Perhaps it is spitting into the wind to ask those who run the National Football League to show a sense of decency regarding the lucrative public trust they hold. Goodell’s taking some $30 million from an enterprise made more profitable because it hides behind its tax-exempt status does not seem materially different from, say, the Fannie Mae CEO’s taking a gigantic bonus while taxpayers were bailing out his company.

Perhaps it is spitting into the wind to expect a son to be half what his father was. Charles Goodell, a member of the House of Representatives for New York from 1959 to 1968 and then a senator until 1971, was renowned as a man of conscience—among the first members of Congress to oppose the Vietnam War, one of the first Republicans to fight for environmental protection. My initial experience with politics was knocking on doors for Charles Goodell; a brown-and-white Senator Goodell campaign button sits in my mementos case. Were Charles Goodell around today, what would he think of his son’s cupidity? Roger Goodell has become the sort of person his father once opposed—an insider who profits from his position while average people pay.

I wanted to put questions about the NFL’s finances to Roger Goodell. When I was researching my book The King of Sports, from which this excerpt is drawn, I requested interview time with Goodell, and he agreed. When NFL headquarters learned that my questions would cover tax exemptions and health issues in the league, the interview was promptly canceled. League spokesman Greg Aiello told me it was not in the NFL’s “best interests” to discuss safety or subsidies.

One might suppose that with football raking in such phenomenal sums of cash, politicians could win votes by assuming populist stances regarding NFL subsidies and exemptions. Instead, in almost every instance, Congress and state legislatures have rolled over and played dead for pro football. NFL owners pressure local politicians with veiled threats of moving teams, though no franchise has moved since 1998. Public officials who back football-stadium spending, meanwhile, can make lavish (if unrealistic) promises of jobs and tourism, knowing the invoices won’t come due until after they have left office.

Roger Goodell has become the sort of person his father once opposed—an insider who profits from his position while average people pay.
Politicians seem more interested in receiving campaign donations and invitations to luxury boxes than in taking on the football powers that be to bargain for a fair deal for ordinary people. Arlen Specter of Pennsylvania, a moderate who served 30 years in the Senate, tried to pressure the NFL to stop picking the public’s pocket, but left Capitol Hill in 2011 and passed away the next year. No populist champion so far has replaced him. Specter told me in 2007, “The NFL owners are arrogant people who have abused the public trust, and act like they can get away with anything.”

Too often, NFL owners can, in fact, get away with anything. In financial terms, the most important way they do so is by creating game images in publicly funded stadiums, broadcasting the images over public airwaves, and then keeping all the money they receive as a result. Football fans know the warning intoned during each NFL contest: that use of the game’s images “without the NFL’s consent” is prohibited. Under copyright law, entertainment created in publicly funded stadiums is private property.

When, for example, Fox broadcasts a Tampa Bay Buccaneers game from Raymond James Stadium, built entirely at the public’s expense, it has purchased the right to do so from the NFL. In a typical arrangement, taxpayers provide most or all of the funds to build an NFL stadium. The team pays the local stadium authority a modest rent, retaining the exclusive right to license images on game days. The team then sells the right to air the games. Finally, the NFL asserts a copyright over what is broadcast. No federal or state law prevents images generated in facilities built at public expense from being privatized in this manner.

Baseball, basketball, ice hockey, and other sports also benefit from this same process. But the fact that others take advantage of the public too is no justification. The NFL’s sweetheart deal is by far the most valuable: This year, CBS, DirecTV, ESPN, Fox, NBC, and Verizon will pay the NFL about $4 billion for the rights to broadcast its games. Next year, that figure will rise to more than $6 billion. Because football is so popular, its broadcast fees would be high no matter how the financial details were structured. The fact that game images created in places built and operated at public expense can be privatized by the NFL inflates the amounts kept by NFL owners, executives, coaches, and players, while driving up the cable fees paid by people who may not even care to watch the games.

In too many areas of contemporary life, public subsidies are converted to private profit. Sometimes, such as with the bailout of General Motors, once the subsidies end, society is better off; sometimes, as with the bailout of AIG, subsidies are repaid. Public handouts for modern professional football never end and are never repaid. In return, the NFL creates nothing of social value—while setting bad examples, despite its protests to the contrary, regarding concussions, painkiller misuse, weight gain, and cheating, among other issues. The No. 1 sport in a nation with a childhood-obesity epidemic celebrates weight gain; that’s bad enough. Worse, the sport setting the bad example is subsidized up one side and down the other.

The NFL’s nonprofit status should be revoked. And lawmakers—ideally in Congress, to level the national playing field, as it were—should require that television images created in publicly funded sports facilities cannot be privatized. The devil would be in the details of any such action. But Congress regulates health care, airspace, and other far-more-complex aspects of contemporary life; it can crack the whip on the NFL.

If football images created in places funded by taxpayers became public domain, the league would respond by paying the true cost of future stadiums—while negotiating to repay construction subsidies already received. To do otherwise would mean the loss of billions in television-rights fees. Pro football would remain just as exciting and popular, but would no longer take advantage of average people.

In 2010, the National Football League moved its annual Pro Bowl away from Honolulu for the first time in 30 years. At the very time Hawaii was cutting its budget for public schools, state lawmakers voted to pay the NFL $4 million per game to bring the event back to their capital. The lawmakers’ gift-giving was bad enough. What was disgraceful was that the rich, subsidized owners of the NFL accepted.

Until public attitudes change, those at the top of the pro-football pyramid will keep getting away with whatever they can. This is troubling not just because ordinary people are taxed so a small number of NFL owners and officers can live as modern feudal lords and ladies. It is troubling because athletics are supposed to set an example—and the example being set by the NFL is one of selfishness.

Football is the king of sports. Should the favorite sport of the greatest nation really be one whose economic structure is based on inequality and greed?

Gregg Easterbrook is a contributing editor at The Atlantic. He writes the Tuesday Morning Quarterback column for ESPN.com and has been an on-air football commentator for ESPN and for the NFL Network. This story is adapted from The King of Sports: Football’s Impact on America, out this month.
 
As an Amazon Associate we earn from qualifying purchases.

Users who are viewing this thread

Back
Top Bottom